翻訳と辞書
Words near each other
・ Herbert S. Walters
・ Herbert S. White
・ Herbert Saffir
・ Herbert Salt
・ Herbert Salter
・ Herbert Samuel Holt
・ Herbert Samuel, 1st Viscount Samuel
・ Herbert Sandberg
・ Herbert Sandberg (conductor)
・ Herbert Sander
・ Herbert Sanders
・ Herbert Sandler
・ Herbert Sausgruber
・ Herbert Sawyer
・ Herbert Sawyer (Royal Navy officer, died 1798)
Herbert Scarf
・ Herbert Schade
・ Herbert Scheetz
・ Herbert Scheibe
・ Herbert Scheinberg
・ Herbert Schibukat
・ Herbert Schilder
・ Herbert Schildt
・ Herbert Schiller
・ Herbert Schmeck
・ Herbert Schmertz
・ Herbert Schmidt
・ Herbert Schmidt (Fallschirmjäger)
・ Herbert Schmidt Ostheim
・ Herbert Schneider


Dictionary Lists
翻訳と辞書 辞書検索 [ 開発暫定版 ]
スポンサード リンク

Herbert Scarf : ウィキペディア英語版
Herbert Scarf

Herbert Eli Scarf (July 25, 1930 – November 15, 2015) was an American economist and Sterling Professor (Emeritus as of 2010) of Economics at Yale University. He is a member of the American Academy of Arts and Sciences, the National Academy of Sciences and the American Philosophical Society. He served as the president of the Econometric Society in 1983. He received both the Frederick Lanchester Award in 1973 and the John von Neumann Medal in 1983 from the Operations Research Society of America and was elected as a Distinguished Fellow of the American Economic Association in 1991.
Scarf never received formal training in economics. Both his undergraduate training at Temple University and his graduate work at Princeton University were in mathematics. For the past five decades, however, he has worked at the frontiers of both economic theory and operations research and has made a number of extraordinarily significant contributions to both of these fields. He is internationally famous for his early epoch-making work on optimal inventory policies and his highly influential study with Andrew Clark on optimal policies for a multi-echelon inventory problem, which initiated the important and flourishing field of supply chain management. Equally, he has gained world recognition for his classic study on the stability of the Walrasian price adjustment processes, his fundamental analysis (with Gerard Debreu) on the relation between the core and the set of competitive equilibria (the so-called Edgeworth conjecture, named after the Irish economist, Francis Ysidro Edgeworth, Feb 8, 1845–Feb 13, 1926), his remarkable sufficient condition (i.e., balancedness) for the existence of a core in non-transferable utility games and general exchange economies, his seminal paper with Lloyd Shapley on housing markets, and his pioneering study on increasing returns and models of production in the presence of indivisibilities. All in all, however, the name of Scarf is always remembered as a synonym for the computation of economic equilibria and fixed points. In the early 1960s he invented a path-breaking technique for computing equilibrium prices. This method is nowadays known as Scarf’s algorithm and has made general equilibrium theory applicable to large, realistic economic problems. This work has generated a major research field in economics termed Applied General Equilibrium Analysis and a corresponding area in operations research known as Simplicial Fixed Point Methods (or Algorithms). Scarf’s algorithm and its subsequent refinements and alternatives have become practical tools for assessing the consequences for the entire economy of a change in the economic environment or a major change in economic policy – to engage in comparative statics when the model of equilibrium is too large to be solved graphically or by simple numerical calculations.
==Early life and Education==
Scarf was born on July 25, 1930, in Philadelphia, Pennsylvania, to parents of Ukrainian Jewish origins. His father Louis Harris Scarf immigrated to the United
States in 1905 from Ukraine at the age of 18 and his mother Lena Elkman also came to the US in the same year at the age of 5. They married in 1929 and had two twin sons next year: Frederick Leonard Scarf and Herbert Eli Scarf. Herbert and Frederick went to the same public primary and high schools in Philadelphia. Herbert Scarf became very interested in mathematics in his early adolescence after reading the book: Men of Mathematics by E.T.Bell. He began to read calculus, geometry, number theory and theoretical mechanics by himself in high school. Herbert’s teachers at the South Philadelphia High School apparently did not know he had such avid mathematical interests, and were astonished when he was ranked first in the Pennsylvania Statewide Mathematical Tournament for high school students organized by Temple University in 1947.
Herbert Scarf and his brother Frederick went to Temple University in 1948 for their undergraduate education. During their undergraduate studies, they lived with their parents and commuted by subway between their parents’ house and the university. Their father had a small business but was hit badly by the Great Depression and did not quite recover from it.
At Temple University, Herbert Scarf chose mathematics as his major subject. He started to attend graduate courses on Real and Complex Variables, Analysis, Probability Theory, and Statistics in his sophomore year. He vividly remembers one of the faculty members of the mathematics department, Professor Marie Wurster, who was very kind to him, always encouraged him and spent an enormous amount of time talking to him about mathematical topics. In 1950, he placed in the top 10 of the 1950 William Lowell Putnam Mathematical Competition, the major mathematics competition among universities in the United States and Canada.
In the fall of 1951, Herbert Scarf got a scholarship from Princeton University and went there for his graduate training in mathematics, whereas his brother Frederick went to MIT for graduate study in physics. Frederick ultimately became a distinguished space scientist – he unfortunately died in Moscow at the early age of 57.
Among Scarf’s many classmates at Princeton were Ralph E. Gomory, Lloyd Shapley, John McCarthy, Marvin Minsky, Serge Lang and John Milnor. He also met Martin Shubik who was then a graduate student at the Department of Economics. At that time John Nash and Harold Kuhn had already left Princeton, but Scarf often saw them during their regular returns. At Princeton, Scarf became a close friend of Gomory – they remain friends after these many years and often meet each other. When Scarf was at Princeton, he did not study game theory or economics but knew Martin Shubik, Lloyd Shapley, and John Nash who were actively involved in the early development of game theory.
After World War II, Princeton had become a sanctuary for a large number of world leading scientists who had escaped from Nazi occupied Europe. Among them were Albert Einstein, John von Neumann, and Kurt Gödel. Scarf often saw Einstein strolling with Gödel from Einstein’s office at the Institute for Advanced Studies to his house on Mercer Street. Einstein always smiled benignly but his friend Gödel rarely did.
Scarf published his first scientific article ``Group invariant integration and the fundamental theorem of algebra” in the Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, in May, 1952. He attended Professor Saloman Bochner’s lectures about Haar Measure on Compact Topological Groups. One day Scarf made a sudden connection between this topic and a quite distant theme that he had been thinking about for quite some time. As a result he proposed an entirely novel proof for the fundamental theorem of algebra, stating that every polynomial in a single variable has at least one complex root.
Scarf’s academic adviser was Salomon Bochner. Scarf admired Bochner and maintained a good relationship with him until his death in 1982. Other professors in the Department of Mathematics were Emil Artin, William Feller, Ralph Fox, Solomon Lefschetz and Albert Tucker. Scarf wrote his PhD dissertation on partial differential equations over manifolds and received his PhD in 1954.

抄文引用元・出典: フリー百科事典『 ウィキペディア(Wikipedia)
ウィキペディアで「Herbert Scarf」の詳細全文を読む



スポンサード リンク
翻訳と辞書 : 翻訳のためのインターネットリソース

Copyright(C) kotoba.ne.jp 1997-2016. All Rights Reserved.